FRBNY Economic Policy Review / July 2012 21
The Rise of the Originate-
to-Distribute Model
and the Role of Banks in
Financial Intermediation
1.Introduction
istorically, banks used deposits to fund loans that they
then kept on their balance sheets until maturity. Over
time, however, this model of banking started to change. Banks
began expanding their funding sources to include bond
financing, commercial paper financing, and repurchase
agreement (repo) funding. They also began to replace their
traditional originate-to-hold model of lending with the so-
called originate-to-distribute model. Initially, banks limited
the distribution model to mortgages, credit card credits, and
car and student loans, but over time they started to apply it
to corporate loans. This article documents how banks adopted
the originate-to-distribute model in their corporate lending
business and provides evidence of the effect that this shift has
had on the growth of nonbank financial intermediation.
Banks first started “distributing” the corporate loans they
originated by syndicating loans and also by selling them in the
secondary loan market.
1
More recently, the growth of the
market for collateralized loan obligations (CLOs) has provided
1
In loan syndications, the lead bank usually retains a portion of the loan and
places the remaining balance with a number of additional investors, usually
other banks. This arrangement is made in conjunction with, and as part of,
the loan origination process. In contrast, the secondary loan market is a
seasoned market in which a bank, including lead banks and syndicate
participants, can subsequently sell an existing loan (or part of a loan).
banks with yet another venue for distributing the loans that
they originate. In principle, banks could create CLOs using the
loans they originated, but it appears they prefer to use collateral
managers—usually investment management companies—that
put together CLOs by acquiring loans, some at the time of
syndication and others in the secondary loan market.
2
Banks’ increasing use of the originate-to-distribute model
has been critical to the growth of the syndicated loan market,
of the secondary loan market, and of collateralized loan
obligations in the United States. The syndicated loan market
rose from a mere $339 billion in 1988 to $2.2 trillion in 2007,
the year the market reached its peak. The secondary loan
market, in turn, evolved from a market in which banks
participated occasionally, most often by selling loans to other
banks through individually negotiated deals, to an active,
dealer-driven market where loans are sold and traded much
like other debt securities that trade over the counter. The
volume of loan trading increased from $8 billion in 1991 to
$176 billion in 2005.
3
The securitization of corporate loans also
experienced spectacular growth in the years that preceded the
financial crisis. Before 2003, the annual volume of new CLOs
issued in the United States rarely surpassed $20 billion. After
2
According to the Securities Industry and Financial Markets Association,
97 percent of corporate loan CLOs in 2007 were structured by financial
institutions that did not originate the loans.
Vitaly M. Bord and João A. C. Santos
Vitaly M. Bord is a former associate economist and João A. C. Santos
a vice president at the Federal Reserve Bank of New York.
Correspondence: joao.santos@ny.frb.org
The authors thank Nicola Cetorelli, Stavros Peristiani, an anonymous reviewer,
and participants at a Federal Reserve Bank of New York seminar for useful
comments. The views expressed are those of the authors and do not necessarily
reflect the position of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York or the Federal
Reserve System.
H
22 The Rise of the Originate-to-Distribute Model
that, loan securitization grew rapidly, topping $180 billion
in 2007.
Investigating the extent of U.S. banks’ adoption of the
originate-to-distribute model in corporate lending has proved
difficult because of data limitations. Thomson Reuters Loan
Pricing Corporation’s DealScan database, arguably the most
comprehensive data source on the syndicated loan market and
the source used by many researchers in the past, imposes
serious limitations on the investigation of this issue. This
database includes information available only at the time of loan
origination, making it impossible to use it to investigate what
happens to the loan after origination. Furthermore, DealScan
has very limited information on investors’ loan shares at the
time of origination. The information on the credit shares
that each syndicate participant holds is sparse, and even the
information on the share that the lead bank—the bank that sets
the terms of the loan—retains at origination is missing for
71 percent of all DealScan credits.
The Loan Syndication Trading Association database
contains micro information on the loans traded in the
secondary market, but it has no information about the identity
of the seller(s) or buyer(s), ruling out its use to close the
information gaps in DealScan. Financial statements filed with
the Federal Reserve, in turn, contain information only on the
credit that banks keep on their balance sheets and thus cannot
be used to ascertain the volume of credit that banks originate.
These statements contain information on the loans that banks
hold for sale, but, as Cetorelli and Peristiani (2012) explain in
detail elsewhere in this volume, this variable provides limited
information on the extent to which banks have replaced the
originate-to-hold model with the originate-to-distribute
model in their lending business.
4
We rely instead on a novel data source, the Shared National
Credit program (SNC) run by the Federal Deposit Insurance
Corporation, the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System, and the Office of the Comptroller of the Currency. Like
DealScan, the SNC program is dominated by syndicated loans.
In contrast to DealScan, however, the SNC program tracks
3
Researchers have suggested several explanations for the development of the
secondary market, including the capital standards introduced with the 1988
Basel Accord (Altman, Gande, and Saunders 2004), the standardization of
loan documentation and settlement procedures that came about with the
establishment of the Loan Syndication Trading Association in 1995 (Hugh and
Wang 2004), and the increase in demand and liquidity resulting from the
increasing involvement of institutional investors (Yago and McCarthy 2004).
See Gorton and Haubrich (1990) for a detailed description of the loan-sales
market in the 1980s.
4
This variable does not distinguish corporate loans from all the other loans
that banks may intend to sell. Further, since there is no information on when
the loans held for sale were originated, ascertaining banks’ relative use of the
originate-to-distribute model based on this variable is difficult. Lastly, the
variable reports only the loans that banks “intend” to sell, not the actual
loans that they sold.
loans over time, and it has complete information on investors’
loan shares over the life of the credit. We discuss the SNC
database in more detail in the data section.
Our study of the change in banks’ corporate lending model
yields a number of significant findings. Although the data
indicate that lead banks increasingly used the originate-to-
distribute model from the early 1990s on, we conclude that this
increase was limited to a large extent to term loans; in their
credit-line business with corporations, banks continued to rely
on the traditional originate-to-hold model. Further, we find
that lead banks increasingly “distributed” their term loans by
selling larger portions of them not only at the time of the loan
origination, but also in the years after origination. For example,
in 1988, the first year of our sample, lead banks retained in
aggregate 21 percent of the term loans they originated that year.
In 2007, lead banks retained only 6.7 percent of the term loans
originated in that year. By 2010, lead banks had managed to
further lower their share in the credits they had originated in
2007 to 3.4 percent.
Our investigation into the entities investing in bank loans
confirms that other banks were not quick to step in and take
over as lead banks reduced their stake in the loans they
originated. Instead, we find that new loan investors, including
investment managers and CLOs, increasingly assumed
control of the credit business. In 1993, all together, nonbank
investors acquired 13.2 percent of the term loans originated
that year. In 2007, they acquired 56.3 percent of the term
loans originated in that year, a 327 percentage point increase
from fifteen years earlier.
The trends documented in this article have important
implications. Banks’ increasing use of the originate-to-
distribute model in their term-lending business will lead to a
transfer of important portions of credit risk out of the banking
system. In the process, however, it will contribute to the growth
of financial intermediation outside the banking system,
including a larger role for unregulated “shadow banking”
institutions.
5
It will also, over time, make the credit kept by
banks on their balance sheets less representative of the still-
essential role they perform in financial intermediation.
In addition, banks’ increasing use of the originate-to-
distribute model could lead to some weakening of lending
standards. According to several theories—including those of
Ramakrishnan and Thakor (1984), Diamond (1984), and
Holmström and Tirole (1993)—banks add value because of
their comparative advantage in monitoring borrowers. To
carry out this task properly, banks must hold the loans they
originate until maturity. If they instead anticipate keeping only
a small portion of a loan, their incentives to screen loan
5
See Pozsar et al. (2010) for a detailed account of the growth of shadow
banking in the United States.
FRBNY Economic Policy Review / July 2012 23
applicants properly and to design the terms of the loan contract
will diminish.
6
They will also have less incentive to monitor
borrowers during the life of the loan.
7
The growth of the
CLO business has likely exacerbated these risks because
CLO investors invest in new securities that depend on the
performance of the “reference portfolio,” which is made up
of many loans, often originated by different banks.
8
Banks’ adoption of the originate-to-distribute model may
also hinder the ability of corporate borrowers to renegotiate
their loans after they have been issued.
9
This difficulty may
arise not only because the borrower will have to renegotiate
with more investors but also because the universe of investors
acquiring corporate loans is more heterogeneous.
Finally, our evidence that banks continue to use the
traditional originate-to-hold model in the provision of credit
lines supports the argument that banks retain a unique ability
to provide liquidity to corporations, possibly because of their
access to deposit funding.
10
Our findings are in line with the
theories advanced by Holmström and Tirole (1998) and
Kashyap, Rajan, and Stein (2002) concerning banks’ liquidity
provision to corporations. Still, as Santos (2012) documents,
banks’ provision of liquidity to depositors and corporations
exposes them to a risk of concurrent runs on both sides of their
balance sheets.
The remainder of our article is organized as follows.
The next section presents our data and methodology and
characterizes our sample. Section 3 documents U.S. banks’
transition from the originate-to-hold model to the originate-
to-distribute model in corporate lending over the past two
decades. Section 4 identifies the relative role of the various
investors that increasingly buy the credit originated by
banks. Section 5 summarizes our findings and their larger
implications.
6
See Pennacchi (1988) and Gorton and Pennacchi (1995) for models that
capture these moral hazard problems.
7
Recent studies, including Sufi (2007), Ivashina (2009), and Focarelli, Pozzolo,
and Casolaro (2008), document that lead banks in loan syndicates use the
retained share to align their incentives with those of syndicate participants
and commit to future monitoring.
8
See Bord and Santos (2010) for evidence that the rise of the CLO business
contributed to riskier lending.
9
Borrowers often renegotiate their credits to adjust the terms of their loans
(Roberts and Sufi 2009) or to manage the maturity they have left in their credits
(Mian and Santos 2011).
10
See Gatev, Schuermann, and Strahan (2009) and Gatev and Strahan (2006)
for empirical evidence in support of banks’ dual liquidity role to depositors
and corporations.
2. Data, Methodology, and Sample
Characterization
2.1 Data
Our main data source for this project is the Shared National
Credit program, run by the Federal Deposit Insurance
Corporation, the Federal Reserve Board, and the Office
of the Comptroller of the Currency. At the end of each year,
the SNC program gathers confidential information on all
credits that exceed $20 million and are held by three or more
federally supervised institutions.
11
For each credit, the SNC program reports the identity of the
borrower, the type of the credit (term loan or credit line, for
example), purpose (such as working capital, mergers, or
acquisitions), amount, maturity date, and rating. In addition,
the program reports information on the lead arranger and
syndicate participants, including their identities and the share
of the credit they hold.
The SNC data fit nicely with our goal of investigating
the role that banks continue to play in the origination of
corporate credit in the United States and the role they have
played in the growth of financial intermediation outside the
banking system. Since the SNC program gathers information
on each syndicated credit at the end of every year, we can link
credits over time and determine the portion of each credit
that stays in the banking sector and the portion acquired by
nonbank financial institutions both at the time of the credit
origination and in each subsequent year during the life of
the credit. In addition, since we have this information over
the past two decades, we can investigate how the relative
importance of the various players in the syndicated loan
market has evolved over time.
We complement the SNC data with information from the
Moody’s Structured Finance Default Risk Service Database and
from Standard and Poor’s Capital IQ. The Moody’s database
has information on structured finance products, including the
size, origination date, and names. We rely on the Moody’s
database to identify CLOs among the syndicate participants
reported in the SNC program that do not have the letters CLO
in their names. We use the Capital IQ database to identify
private equity firms, hedge funds, and mutual funds among
the syndicate participants.
11
The confidential data were processed solely within the Federal Reserve
for the analysis presented in this article.
24 The Rise of the Originate-to-Distribute Model
2.2 Methodology
Our investigation into the effect of the originate-to-distribute
model on the importance of banks in financial intermediation
has two parts. We begin by investigating how the rise of that
model affected the portion of each credit that the lead bank
retains during the life of the credit. To this end, for each credit
in the SNC program, we first compute the portion that the lead
bank retains on its balance sheet at origination. Next, because
banks sometimes sell or securitize part of their credits after they
originate them, we compute the portion of the credit that the
lead bank still retains on its balance sheet three years after the
origination year.
In the second part of our investigation, we identify the
buyers of bank credits and how the role of the various buyers
has changed over the past two decades. For each credit, we
compute the portion that the lead bank sells to other banks
and the portion that it sells outside the banking sector,
distinguishing in the latter case whether the acquiring
institution is an insurance company, a finance company, a
pension fund, an investment manager, a private equity firm,
a CLO, or a broker or investment bank. This part of our
investigation allows us to pin down the role that banks have
played in the growth of financial intermediation outside the
banking system in general and their role in the growth of
shadow banking in particular.
Because the nature of the credit contract may affect
the lead bank’s ability to sell or securitize the credit, we
distinguish between term loans and credit lines throughout
our investigation. For a similar reason, we also categorize the
credits according to their purpose: that is, whether they are
to fund mergers and acquisitions or capital expenditures
or whether they are to serve corporate purposes.
2.3 Sample Characterization
Our sample covers the period 1988-2010. On average, we
observe 7,432 credits each year. Of these, 1,758 are new credits
originated in the year, and 5,674 are credits originated in prior
years. Even though the criteria for inclusion of a credit in the
SNC program remained unchanged throughout the sample
period, inflation and growth over the past two decades
contributed to an upward trend in the number of credits in the
SNC database. In 1989, the SNC database had 5,402 credits, of
which 1,368 were originated in that year. In 2007, at the peak
of the business cycle, it had 8,248 credits, of which 2,114 were
originated in that year.
To get a better sense of the SNC database coverage, we
compare the annual value of credits included in that database
with the annual value of credits in DealScan, the database
mentioned above that has been extensively used for research on
bank corporate lending in recent years.
12
Chart 1 reports the
annual value of new credits—that is, credits originated in each
year—in the SNC database and the annual value of credits
reported in DealScan. Since SNC covers only credits above
$20 million, we also report the annual value of credits in
DealScan above that threshold. To make the information from
the two databases even more comparable, we further adjust the
information reported from DealScan by excluding credits that
are classified as “restatements” of previous credits, since this
indicates a renegotiation of an existing credit.
13
From Chart 1, it is apparent that both databases pick up the
positive trend in the volume of credit as well as the effect of the
three recessions in the United States during the sample period
(1990-91, 2001, and 2008-09). It is also clear that the main
difference between the two databases is that DealScan reports
information on new credits as well as information on renegoti-
ations of existing credits. The fact that SNC reports only credits
above $20 million while DealScan contains information on
credits above $100,000 does not constitute an important
difference between the two databases. When we adjust the
information reported in DealScan to “match” the credits
reported in the SNC database, the difference between the
two databases becomes very small. On average, each
year the volume of credit reported in the SNC database
is 37.2 percent of that reported in DealScan. When we restrict
the credits in DealScan to those above $20 million, that share
increases to 37.8 percent; when we further drop renegotiations
from DealScan, the share rises to 74.4 percent.
12
Examples of papers that use DealScan include Dennis and Mullineaux
(2000), Hubbard, Kuttner, and Palia (2002), Santos and Winton (2008, 2010),
Hale and Santos (2009, 2010), Sufi (2007), Bharath et al. (2009), Santos (2011),
Paligorova and Santos (2011), and Bord and Santos (2011).
13
In SNC, renegotiations do not usually give rise to a new credit, while in
DealScan they do.
FRBNY Economic Policy Review / July 2012 25
Chart 1
Loan Volumes Reported in the SNC and DealScan Databases
1990
1995
2000
2005
2010
2,400
2,000
1,600
1,200
800
400
0
Billions of U.S. dollars
SNC Issuance by Year
1990
1995
2000
2005
2010
LPC Issuance by Year
Billions of U.S. dollars
All loans
Sources: Shared National Credit (SNC) database, produced jointly by the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, Board of Governors of the Federal
Reserve System, and Office of the Comptroller of the Currency; DealScan database, produced by Thomson Reuters Loan Pricing Corporation (LPC).
2,200
1,800
1,400
1,000
600
200
2,400
2,000
1,600
1,200
800
400
0
2,200
1,800
1,400
1,000
600
200
Loans of greater than
$20 million, excluding
renegotiations
Loans of greater
than $20 million
3. From Originate-to-Hold
to Originate-to-Distribute
In traditional banking, banks originate credits and hold them
on their balance sheet until their maturity. Over time, however,
banks began to replace the originate-to-hold model with the
originate-to-distribute model, whereby they originate a credit
and sell or securitize a portion of it at the time of origination or
later. In this section, we investigate how the adoption of the
originate-to-distribute model reduced the exposure of banks
to the credits they originated over the past two decades.
3.1 Distribution at the Time of Credit
Origination
To investigate the effect of the originate-to-distribute model
on the exposure of banks to the credits they originate, we begin
by looking at the lead banks’ market share of the credits they
originate, at the time of the credit origination.
For our purposes, “banks” are all institutions that are
regulated and that perform the traditional bank roles of
maturity and credit transformation. Thus, the banks discussed
throughout our article refer to all commercial banks, bank
holding companies (BHCs), thrifts and thrift holding
companies, credit unions, and foreign banking organizations,
including their domestic branches. Note that whether an
institution is classified as a bank may vary over time. For
example, Morgan Stanley and Goldman Sachs are classified as
banks only from January 1, 2009, when they became BHCs. For
the period preceding this date, they are not counted as banks
since they were operating as investment banks.
In 1988, the first year of the sample period, lead banks
retained in aggregate a stake of 17.6 percent of the credits they
originated in that year, including term loans and credit lines
(Chart 2).
14
Beginning in 1990, when they retained in aggregate
22.2 percent, lead banks started to decrease their share of the
credits they originated, reaching a low of 10.5 percent in 1999.
During the 2000s, the aggregate shares varied with the business
cycle but generally remained steady at around 13 percent.
The market share of the credits that lead banks retain at
origination has clearly fallen, but the representation of this
decline in Chart 2 is skewed by the large number of credit lines
in our sample. As we can see from Chart 3, while banks have
increasingly replaced the originate-to-hold model with the
originate-to-distribute model over the past two decades, this
substitution has been far more pronounced in the origination
of term loans than of credit lines. To be sure, this difference was
not immediately apparent: In 1988, lead banks retained in
aggregate 17.6 percent of the credit lines and 21 percent of the
14
Here, and throughout the rest of the article, we use the terms market share
and aggregate share interchangeably. By lead banksmarket or aggregate share,
we mean the share of all credits that the lead banks, taken together, retain.
It is computed as the sum of all the lead banks’ retained credit amounts
divided by the sum of all new credits they originated that year.
26 The Rise of the Originate-to-Distribute Model
Chart 2
Lead Banks’ Market Share of Syndicated Loans
at Credit Origination
0.25
1990
1995
2000
2005
2010
Source: Shared National Credit database, produced jointly by the Federal
Deposit Insurance Corporation, Board of Governors of the Federal
Reserve System, and Office of the Comptroller of the Currency.
Market share
0.30
0.15
0.20
0.10
0
0.05
Chart 3
Lead Banks’ Market Share of Credits at Origination, by Credit Type
Market share
0.25
Credit Lines
1990
1995
2000
2005
2010
Source: Shared National Credit database, produced jointly by the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System,
and Office of the Comptroller of the Currency.
Market share
0.30
0.15
0.20
0.10
0
0.05
0.25
0.30
0.15
0.20
0.10
0
0.05
Term Loans
1990
1995
2000
2005
2010
term loans they extended in that year. These shares declined
to 10.3 percent and 10.0 percent, respectively, by 1999.
However, in the first decade of the 2000s, while lead banks
continued the trend of decreasing their market share of term
loans, they reversed the trend for credit lines. By 2006, the last
year before the data pick up the effects of the most recent
financial crisis, lead banks increased their market share of the
credit lines they originated to 14.1 percent but decreased their
market share of the term loans they originated to 8.8 percent.
These aggregate trends are consistent with the trends in the
average share of the credit that the lead bank retains on its
balance sheet. This share was equal to 32 percent for credit
lines in 1988 and 31 percent for term loans in the same
year. By 1999, these shares had declined to 17 percent and
16 percent, respectively. Then, in the first decade of the new
century, the average credit-line share retained by the lead
bank increased to 24 percent by 2006, whereas the average
share retained in term loans increased slightly but essentially
remained stable, at 17 percent, by the same year.
Since average retained shares are much higher than the
aggregate (market) shares, the data indicate that banks tend to
keep smaller shares of the larger credits that they originate.
Recall that the average retained share is a simple average of the
credit shares that banks keep on the balance sheet, while the
aggregate share is a weighted average of these shares, with the
weights defined by the size of the credits.
The disparity between the trends in lead banks’ market
shares of credit lines and term loans shows the effect of banks’
increasing syndication and securitization of term loans. These
trends, though suggestive of these effects, do not reflect the
whole story, since they account only for the role of lead banks
and exclude that of banks that participate in the loan syndicate
(syndicate-participant banks). We discuss this issue further in
a later section.
FRBNY Economic Policy Review / July 2012 27
Chart 4
Lead Banks’ Market Share of Term Loans
at Origination by Credit Purpose
1990
1995
2000
2005
2010
Source: Shared National Credit database, produced jointly by the Federal
Deposit Insurance Corporation, Board of Governors of the Federal
Reserve System, and Office of the Comptroller of the Currency.
Market share
0.4
0.2
0.3
0
0.1
Mergers and
acquisitions
Corporate purposes
Capital expenditures
Chart 5
Lead Banks’ Market Share of Credits at Origination and Three Years Later
Market share
0.25
1990
1995
2000
2005
2010
S
ource: Shared National Credit database, produced jointly by the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System,
and Office of the Comptroller of the Currency.
Market share
0.30
0.15
0.20
0.10
0
0.05
0.25
0.30
0.15
0.20
0.10
0
0.05
1990
1995
2000
2005
2010
Credit Lines
Year 0
Year 3
Term Loans
Year 0
Year 3
Even though banks substituted the originate-to-distribute
model for the originate-to-hold model at a faster pace in their
term-loan business, they did not use the former uniformly
across all types of term loans. For instance, they varied their
retention rates depending on the purpose of the loan, as can
be seen in Chart 4. Over time, banks increasingly used the
originate-to-distribute model when they extended loans for
corporate purposes and in particular to fund mergers and
acquisitions, possibly because of the additional risk such
loans tend to carry. In contrast, they continued to use their
traditional originate-to-hold model when they extended
loans for capital expenditures.
3.2 Distribution after the Credit Origination
The decline in the share of credits that lead banks originate
did not occur only at the time of the credit origination but
continued throughout the life of the credit. To investigate this
effect, we began by selecting cohorts of credits originated each
year that we observed for at least three years. Next, we
computed the market share of the credits that the lead banks
retained at the time of origination and three years later. Both of
these shares are depicted in Chart 5. The left panel shows the
market shares for credit lines, while the right panel shows the
market shares for term loans. To allow us to observe all the
credits for three years, we end the chart with credits originated
in 2007. Recall that our sample ends in 2010.
A quick look at Chart 5 shows two important results. First,
in the years after credit-line origination, lead banks either did
not sell off additional portions of the credit lines or sold off a
very small (aggregate) share. This practice prevailed at the
beginning of our sample period in the late 1980s and continued
throughout the sample period, with the exception of the early-
to-mid-1990s when lead banks seemed to have sold off more
of the credit lines.
28 The Rise of the Originate-to-Distribute Model
Second, as the term loans held by lead banks aged, the
banks increasingly reduced their aggregate exposure to them.
In the previous section, we documented that, over time, lead
banks retained at origination a smaller market share of the
term loans they originated. Chart 5 shows that this decline
continued even after the origination year. For example, of the
term loans that banks originated in 1988, they retained in
aggregate 21.4 percent at origination. Three years later, these
banks had, in aggregate, 18.7 percent of these term loans on
their balance sheet. In 2004, lead banks retained in aggregate
8.6 percent of the term loans they originated in that year.
Three years later, the banks’ aggregate exposure to the same
set of term loans had been reduced to 7.1 percent. In 2007, the
last year in our sample for which we conducted this exercise,
lead banks retained a market share of 6.7 percent of their term
loans at the time of origination. By 2010, they had lowered
their market share of these same term loans to 3.4 percent.
We obtain similar results when we track the individual share
of each credit that the lead bank retains on its balance sheet. For
credit lines, lead banks either decreased their average retained
shares very little or not at all. For example, of the credit lines
originated in 1988, on average banks retained 30.5 percent at
origination and 28.5 percent three years later. In 2004, lead
banks retained, on average, 21.6 percent at origination and
21.2 percent three years later. For term loans, however, lead
banks tended to cut back more of their credit exposure. Of the
term loans originated in 1988, banks retained an average of
35.2 percent at origination and 30.7 percent three years later.
In 2004, banks retained on average 19.2 percent at origination
and 18.0 percent three years later.
In sum, the results reported in this section show that over
the past two decades, banks largely continued to use the
traditional originate-to-hold model when they extended credit
lines to corporations but increasingly switched to the originate-
to-distribute model for term loans. This evidence suggests that
banks have a unique ability to provide liquidity to corporations
by extending credit lines to them. It also highlights the need
to reconsider the measures traditionally used to capture the
importance of banks as providers of credit to corporations.
As banks increasingly adopt the originate-to-distribute model,
conventional measures of bank lending activity, which rely on
the credit kept by banks on their balance sheets, will tend to
understate the role they play in the credit-origination process.
In the next section, we investigate which institutions are buying
the credits that banks originate.
4. Who Buys Bank Credit Lines
and Term Loans?
Given our finding that over time lead banks are retaining a
smaller and smaller portion of the credits they originate
(especially in the case of term loans), a natural question to ask
is, Who buys these credits? Answering this question—and, in
particular, finding out whether banks or other institutional
investors such as pension funds and hedge funds are buying
these credits—is important because these institutions have
quite different monitoring capabilities and incentives for
renegotiating existing credits. Answering this question also
helps us understand the growth of shadow banking in the past
decade and the links of these institutions to the banking sector.
4.1 The Role of Banks as Credit Acquirers
We start by investigating whether, as the lead banks have
lowered the share of credits they retain at origination, other
banks have increased the share of credit they hold as syndicate
participants. The left panel of Chart 6 shows for the total credit
extended under credit lines each year, the portion that lead
banks retained, the portion acquired by banks that are
syndicate participants, and the portion acquired by the
remaining investors. The right panel of the chart reports the
same information for term loans.
As the chart shows, although the market share of credit
lines retained by lead banks decreased through the 1990s and
increased through the 2000s, the total market share held by all
banks (both lead and syndicate-participant banks) remains
fairly stable, at an average of 92 percent during the pre-crisis
sample period. In fact, when lead banks’ market share
decreased in the 1990s, the syndicate-participant banks’
market share increased, and that share increased more than
the lead banks’ share decreased. Similarly, from 2000 to 2010,
syndicate-participant banks’ market share decreased more
than the lead banks’ market share increased. In other words,
credit-line provision continues to be in essence a “bank
business.”
Term loans, however, present a different picture. As we can
see from the right panel of Chart 6, the decline in the lead
banks’ aggregate retained share was accompanied by an even
bigger decline in the share of the term loans acquired by other
banks.
15
15
The picture is fairly similar when we consider the average share held by
banks. For credit lines, the average share held by syndicate-participant banks
remained stable at approximately 10 percent throughout the time period.
By contrast, for term loans, the average share held by syndicate-participant
banks decreased from its peak of 14 percent in 1991 (11 percent in 1988) to
6.3 percent in 2006.
FRBNY Economic Policy Review / July 2012 29
Chart 6
Banks’ Retained Credits at Origination: Lead Banks versus Non-Lead Banks
Market share
1990
1995
2000
2005
2010
Source: Shared National Credit database, produced jointly by the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System,
and Office of the Comptroller of the Currency.
Market share
1.0
0.8
0.6
0.4
0.2
0
Credit Lines
1990
1995
2000
2005
2010
1.0
0.8
0.6
0.4
0.2
0
Term Loans
Lead banks
Syndicate-participant banks
Nonbanks
Chart 7
Syndicate-Participant Banks’ Market Share of Credits at Origination and Three Years Later
Market share
1990
1995
2000
2005
2010
Source: Shared National Credit database, produced jointly by the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System,
and Office of the Comptroller of the Currency.
Market share
0.8
1990
1995
2000
2005
2010
0.6
0.7
0.4
0.5
0.3
0.2
0.1
0
0.9
Credit Lines
0.8
0.6
0.7
0.4
0.5
0.3
0.2
0.1
0
0.9
Term Loans
Year 0
Year 3
Year 0
Year 3
Of the $47 billion in term loans originated in 1988, banks,
including lead banks and syndicate-participant banks, retained
on their balance sheet 88.6 percent of the amount of credit.
Of the $315 billion in term loans originated in 2007, banks
retained on their balance sheet 43.7 percent. Thus, banks (lead
banks and syndicate-participant banks) more than halved their
market share of term loans from 1988 to 2007.
These patterns remain when we consider how the market
share of bank investors changed over the life of the loan. As
Chart 7 shows, syndicate-participant banks did not sell off their
market share of credit lines during the lifetime of the loans but,
apart from short periods in the early 1990s and mid-2000s, they
did decrease their market share of term loans as the loans
matured. In fact, for term loans that we observe for at least
30 The Rise of the Originate-to-Distribute Model
Chart 8
Nonbank Investors’ Market Share by Credit Type
Market share
1990
1995
2000
2005
2010
S
ource: Shared National Credit database, produced jointly by the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System,
and Office of the Comptroller of the Currency.
Market share
0.5
0.4
0.6
0.3
0.2
0
Credit Lines
1990
1995
2000
2005
2010
1.0
0.8
0.6
0.4
0.2
0
Term Loans
0.1
Insurance companies
Collateralized loan obligations
Brokers and investment banks
Investment management firms
Private equity firms
Pension funds
Finance companies
Other
Foreign nonbank organizations
three years, of the $17 billion of such loans originated in 1988,
banks (both lead and syndicate-participant banks) kept on
their balance sheets 90.2 percent in 1988 but only 86.9 percent
three years later. Similarly, of the $17 billion in term loans
issued in 2007, banks kept on their balance sheets 42.1 percent
at origination but only 32.8 percent three years later.
Thus, for credit lines, syndicate-participant banks tended to
offset the actions of the lead banks at origination, and they
tended to hold the credit lines to maturity (or at least for three
years). For term loans, in contrast, syndicate-participant banks,
like lead banks, have been decreasing the market share they
retain at origination and over the years after origination.
16
4.2 The Role of Nonbank Financial
Institutions
Given the decline in the portion of term loans retained in the
banking sector, the next question to ask is, Who are the
investors that have been increasing their presence in this
market? To address this question, we report in Chart 8 the
market shares at the time of credit origination in the credit-
line market (left panel) and the term-loan market (right
16
Interestingly, the average shares for syndicate-participant banks did not
change much over the life of the credit, for both credit lines and term loans.
With the exception of loans originated during the recessions of 1990 and 2001
(for which the average participant bank share decreased over the loans’
lifetime), on average, syndicate-participant banks retained the same share
at origination as three years later.
panel) of the main nonbank investors in these markets:
insurance companies, investment management firms, finance
companies, collateralized loan obligation managers, private
equity firms, brokers and investment banks, pension funds,
and foreign nonbank organizations.
17
Looking at the information on credit lines, we see that the
market share of nonbank investors in credit lines is very small,
less than 10 percent in each year. This finding was expected,
given our previous evidence that banks continue to play a
dominant role in the provision of liquidity to corporations
through credit lines. The nonbank entities that have the highest
market share are finance companies, pension plans, investment
managers, and “other.”
18
Finance companies first appear in
our credit-line data in 1992, when they held a market share
of 0.2 percent. They reached their peak market share in 2002
with 3.2 percent of all credit lines originated.
17
The different categories are identified in a variety of ways: by keyword;
by information from the National Information Center run by the Federal
Reserve System, which identifies banks, bank holding companies, foreign
banking organizations, finance companies, insurance companies, and so on;
by matching to the Moody’s Structured Finance Database, which allows us
to identify CLOs; and by matching to Capital IQ to identify investment
management firms and private equity firms. Investment management firms
are identified as hedge funds, mutual funds, or asset managers. Note that
institutions may shift across categories over time. For example, for most of
our sample, Goldman Sachs and Morgan Stanley are identified as investment
banks. However, after they officially converted their status to BHCs in the
first quarter of 2009, they are classified as BHCs. Finally, note that for the
remaining analysis, we exclude nonbank entities that are part of banking
entities—for example, finance companies that are part of BHCs. (Including
them does not substantially change our analysis.)
FRBNY Economic Policy Review / July 2012 31
Turning our attention to term loans, we see from the right
panel of Chart 8 that finance companies, CLOs, brokers, and
investment managers have been increasing their share in the
market for term loans and that nonbank investors—
particularly, investment managers and CLOs—play a much
bigger role in this market than in the credit-line market.
Investment managers first appear in our data in 1992, when
they acquired 2 percent of the term loans originated that year.
Similarly, CLOs first appear in our data in 1994, when they held
0.3 percent of the term loans originated in that year. By 2007,
these investors had acquired 13.6 percent and 15.5 percent,
respectively, of the term loans issued in that year. Again, note
that all of these numbers underestimate the true presence of
each category in the market since the “other” grouping
contains institutions that could not be accurately matched to
any of the categories from our sources; nonetheless, most of
these institutions probably do fall into one of these categories.
Finance companies first appear in the term-loan data in 1989,
when they acquired 0.03 percent of the term loans issued that
year; at their peak in 1998, they held 7.3 percent of the term
loans issued that year. Private equity firms currently represent
a small share of the market (0.8 percent in 2010), but they have
been steadily building their presence in this market, from
0.4 percent in 1996 to 3 percent in 2007. In contrast, insurance
companies continue to play a minor role: the share of the term
loans held by insurance companies increased from 0.2 percent
in 1988 to 1.0 percent in 2007.
4.3 Nonbank Investors’ Shares
after Loan Origination
We documented earlier that both lead banks and syndicate-
participant banks continue to reduce the share of their term
loans in the years following origination. In Charts 9 through
11, we examine the market shares of the top three nonbank
investors in the syndicated loan market at the time of the credit
origination and three years later. Because these nonbank
investors invest mainly in term loans, we limit our analysis
to the term-loan market.
Finance companies kept their share of the term-loan market
more or less constant over the past decade. In contrast, CLOs
and investment managers have been increasing their market
18
The majority of the institutions in the “other” category were not clearly
identified by our sources as belonging to one of the categories discussed above.
Because much of the identification was done through name matching,
institutions for which the quality of the match was in question were also placed
in the “other” category. Finally, the category also contains a very small number
of Article XII New York investment companies, data processing servicers,
individuals, and foundations.
share of the term-loan business. These investors have been
buying larger portions of the credits at the time of their
origination, and they continue to increase such investments
in the years after origination. From 2000 to 2007, on average,
CLOs acquired 12.6 percent of the term loans originated in
each year, while investment managers acquired on average
Chart 10
Role of Investment Managers
1990
1995
2000
2005
2010
Source: Shared National Credit database, produced jointly by the Federal
Deposit Insurance Corporation, Board of Governors of the Federal
Reserve System, and Office of the Comptroller of the Currency.
Market share
0.30
0.20
0.25
0
0.05
Year 0
Year 3
0.10
0.15
Chart 9
Role of Finance Companies
1990
1995
2000
2005
2010
Source: Shared National Credit database, produced jointly by the Federal
Deposit Insurance Corporation, Board of Governors of the Federal
Reserve System, and Office of the Comptroller of the Currency.
Market share
0.30
0.20
0.25
0
0.05
Year 0
Year 3
0.10
0.15
32 The Rise of the Originate-to-Distribute Model
Chart 11
Role of Collateralized Loan Obligations
1990
1995
2000
2005
2010
Source: Shared National Credit database, produced jointly by the Federal
Deposit Insurance Corporation, Board of Governors of the Federal
Reserve System, and Office of the Comptroller of the Currency.
Market share
0.30
0.20
0.25
0
0.05
Year 0
Year 3
0.10
0.15
8.7 percent of this market. Three years later, such institutions
held 18.2 percent and 12.9 percent of these loans, respectively.
This evidence shows that over the past two decades, as banks
have increasingly opted to retain on their balance sheet a
smaller portion of the term loans they originated, they have
been fueling the growth of nonbank institutions, in particular
CLOs and investment managers.
5. Final Remarks
Our analysis of banks’ role in financial intermediation reveals
that beginning in the early 1990s, lead banks increasingly used
the originate-to-distribute model in their corporate lending
business. This increase, however, was largely limited to term
loans. In general, banks continued to rely on the traditional
originate-to-hold model in the credit-line business. Further,
we find that more and more lead banks “distributed” their
term loans by selling larger portions of them, not only at
the time of the loan origination but also in the years after
origination.
Our investigation into the investors that bought the bank
loans shows that traditional institutional investors and, in
particular, new loan investors—including investment managers
and CLOs—began taking over more of the credit business.
Our findings have several important implications for the
theme of this volume. They show that in evaluating the
importance of banks in financial intermediation, analysts must
use measures of the credit that banks originate, as opposed to
measures of the credit they retain on their balance sheets.
Indeed, our findings confirm that measures of the importance
of banks that rely on the credit held by banks on their balance
sheets will increasingly understate the essential role that banks
play in financial intermediation. Our findings also show that
banks have been an important contributor to the so-called
shadow banking system.
19
For example, in 1993, of the
$22.7 billion in term loans originated, banks sold $2.2 billion to
the shadow banking system. By comparison, in 2007, of the
$315 billion in term loans originated, they sold $125 billion to
the shadow banking system. In about two decades, the annual
volume of term loans that banks supplied to nonaffiliated
shadow-banking institutions increased by $123 billion.
Lastly, our findings suggest some interesting questions
for future research. Does the increasing presence of nonbank
financial institutions in loan syndicates affect lending terms or
hinder borrowers’ ability to renegotiate their credits? Does the
decline in a lead bank’s retained share of the credits it originates
affect the nature of its relationship with borrowers? What are
the implications of the decline in a bank’s retained share for its
incentives to assess the creditworthiness of loan applicants or
to track the viability of loans? Researchers have been using the
share of a credit held by the lead bank at the time of origination
as a proxy for the bank’s monitoring incentives. As our
evidence shows, however, this share may be a biased proxy
for the bank’s exposure during the life of a loan. It would be
interesting to investigate the implications of the decline in the
bank’s credit share for its monitoring incentives during the life
of the credit.
19
For these computations, “shadow banking institutions” are defined as CLOs,
brokers and investment banks, investment managers, private equity firms,
finance companies, and foreign nonbank institutions.
References
FRBNY Economic Policy Review / July 2012 33
Altman, E. I., A. Gande, and A. Saunders. 2004. “Informational
Efficiency of Loans versus Bonds: Evidence from Secondary
Market Prices.” New York University Working Paper
no. S-FI-04-02, February. Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/
abstract=1297736.
Bharath, S. T., S. Dahiya, A. Saunders, and A. Srinivasan. 2009.
“Lending Relationships and Loan Contract Terms.” Working
paper, New York University Stern School of Business.
Bord, V. M., and J. A. C. Santos. 2010. “Did the Rise of CLOs Lead
to Riskier Lending?” Unpublished paper, Federal Reserve Bank
of New York.
———. 2011. “Banks’ Liquidity and the Cost of Liquidity to
Corporations.” Unpublished paper, Federal Reserve Bank
of New York, September.
Cetorelli, N., and S. Peristiani. 2012. “The Role of Banks in Asset
Securitization.” Federal Reserve Bank of New York Economic
Policy Review 18, no. 2 (July): 47-63.
Dennis, S. A., and D. J. Mullineaux. 2000. “Syndicated Loans.”
Journal of Financial Intermediation 9, no. 4 (October):
404-26.
Diamond, D. W. 1984. “Financial Intermediation and Delegated
Monitoring.” Review of Economic Studies 51, no. 3 (July):
393-414.
Focarelli, D., A. F. Pozzolo, and L. Casolaro. 2008. “The Pricing Effect
of Certification on Bank Loans: Evidence from the Syndicated
Credit Market.” Journal of Monetary Economics 55, no. 2
(March): 335-49.
Gatev, E., and P. Strahan. 2006. “Banks’ Advantage in Hedging
Liquidity Risk: Theory and Evidence from the Commercial Paper
Market.” Journal of Finance 61, no. 2 (April): 867-92.
Gatev, E., T. Schuermann, and P. E. Strahan. 2009. “Managing Bank
Liquidity Risk: How Deposit-Loan Synergies Vary with Market
Conditions.” Review of Financial Studies 22, no. 3 (March):
995-1020.
Gorton, G. B., and J. G. Haubrich. 1990. “The Loan Sales Market.”
Research in Financial Services 2: 85-135.
Gorton, G. B., and G. G. Pennacchi. 1995. “Banks and Loan Sales:
Marketing Nonmarketable Assets.” Journal of Monetary
Economics 35, no. 3 (June): 389-411.
Hale, G. B., and J. A. C. Santos. 2009. “Do Banks Price Their
Informational Monopoly?” Journal of Financial
Economics 93, no. 2 (August): 185-206.
———. 2010. “Do Banks Propagate Debt Market Shocks?”
Unpublished paper, Federal Reserve Bank of New York, February.
Holmström, B. R., and J. Tirole. 1993. “Market Liquidity and
Performance Monitoring.” Journal of Political Economy 101,
no. 4 (August): 678-709.
———. 1998. “Private and Public Supply of Liquidity.” Journal
of Political Economy 106, no. 1 (February): 1-40.
Hubbard, R. G., K. N. Kuttner, and D. N. Palia. 2002. “Are There Bank
Effects in Borrowers’ Costs of Funds? Evidence from a Matched
Sample of Borrowers and Banks.” Journal of Business 75, no. 4
(October): 559-81.
Hugh, T., and Z. Wang. 2004. “The Integration of Bank Syndicated
Loan and Junk Bond Markets.”
Journal of Banking and
Finance 28, no. 2 (February): 299-329.
Ivashina, V. 2009. “Asymmetric Information Effects on Loan
Spreads.” Journal of Financial Economics 92, no. 2 (May):
300-19.
Kashyap, A. K., R. G. Rajan, and J. C. Stein. 2002. “Banks as Liquidity
Providers: An Explanation for the Coexistence of Lending and
Deposit-Taking.” Journal of Finance 57, no. 1 (February):
33-73.
Mian, A., and J. A. C. Santos. 2011. “Liquidity Risk and Maturity
Management over the Credit Cycle.” Unpublished paper, Federal
Reserve Bank of New York.
Paligorova, T., and J. A. C. Santos. 2011. “When Is It Less Costly for
Risky Firms to Borrow? Evidence from the Bank Risk-Taking
Channel of Monetary Policy.” Unpublished paper, Federal Reserve
Bank of New York.
References (Continued)
34 The Rise of the Originate-to-Distribute Model
Pennacchi, G. G. 1988. “Loan Sales and the Cost of Bank Capital.”
Journal of Finance 43, no. 2 (March-April): 375-96.
Pozsar, Z., T. Adrian, A. Ashcraft, and H. Boesky. 2010. “Shadow
Banking.” Federal Reverse Bank of New York Staff Reports,
no. 458, July.
Ramakrishnan, R. T. S., and A. V. Thakor. 1984. “Information
Reliability and a Theory of Financial Intermediation.” Review
of Economic Studies 51, no. 3 (July): 415-32.
Roberts, M., and A. Sufi. 2009. “Renegotiation of Financial Contracts:
Evidence from Private Credit Agreements.” Journal of
Financial Economics 93, no. 2 (August): 159-84.
Santos, J. A. C. 2011. “Bank Loan Pricing following the Subprime
Crisis.” Review of Financial Studies 24, no. 6 (June): 1916-43.
———. 2012. “Banks’ Liquidity Insurance Provision to Firms and
Depositors and the Risk of Cìoncurrent Runs on Their Assets
and Liabilities.” Unpublished paper, Federal Reserve Bank
of New York.
Santos, J. A. C., and A. Winton. 2008. “Bank Loans, Bonds, and
Informational Monopolies across the Business Cycle.” Journal
of Finance 63, no. 3 (June): 1315-59.
———. 2010. “Bank Capital, Borrower Power, and Loan Rates.”
Unpublished paper, Federal Reserve Bank of New York.
Sufi, A. 2007. “Information Asymmetry and Financing Arrangements:
Evidence from Syndicated Loans.” Journal of Finance 62, no. 2
(April): 629-68.
Yago, G., and D. McCarthy. 2004. “The U.S. Leveraged Loan Market:
A Primer.” Milken Institute, October.
The views expressed are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the position of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York
or the Federal Reserve System. The Federal Reserve Bank of New York provides no warranty, express or implied, as to the
accuracy, timeliness, completeness, merchantability, or fitness for any particular purpose of any information contained in
documents produced and provided by the Federal Reserve Bank of New York in any form or manner whatsoever.